Thursday, September 10, 2009

Joint Ownership of the Means of Production? (John Paul II series)

This selection from Laborem exercers shows John Paul II embracing the "middle way" of distributism. he argues against socialist collectivist and state control of the means of production, as well as those forms of capitalism that would deby labor the right to ownership of the means to produce. He insists on the right to private property but not on the absolute right divorced form the higher good of the common good of a society of persons. My guess is there's something here to annoy everyone:

". . . the Church, diverges radically from the programme of collectivism as proclaimed by Marxism and put into pratice in various countries in the decades following the time of Leo XIII's Encyclical. At the same time it differs from the programme of capitalism practised by liberalism and by the political systems inspired by it. In the latter case, the difference consists in the way the right to ownership or property is understood. Christian tradition has never upheld this right as absolute and untouchable. On the contrary, it has always understood this right within the broader context of the right common to all to use the goods of the whole of creation: the right to private property is subordinated to the right to common use, to the fact that goods are meant for everyone.

"Furthermore, in the Church's teaching, ownership has never been understood in a way that could constitute grounds for social conflict in labour. As mentioned above, property is acquired first of all through work in order that it may serve work. This concerns in a special way ownership of the means of production. Isolating these means as a separate property in order to set it up in the form of "capital" in opposition to "labour"-and even to practise exploitation of labour-is contrary to the very nature of these means and their possession. They cannot be possessed against labour, they cannot even be possessed for possession's sake, because the only legitimate title to their possession- whether in the form of private ownership or in the form of public or collective ownership-is that they should serve labour, and thus, by serving labour, that they should make possible the achievement of the first principle of this order, namely, the universal destination of goods and the right to common use of them. . . .

". . . The principle of respect for work demands that this right should undergo a constructive revision, both in theory and in practice. If it is true that capital, as the whole of the means of production, is at the same time the product of the work of generations, it is equally true that capital is being unceasingly created through the work done with the help of all these means of production, and these means can be seen as a great workbench at which the present generation of workers is working day after day. Obviously we are dealing here with different kinds of work, not only so-called manual labour but also the many forms of intellectual work, including white-collar work and management.

"In the light of the above, the many proposals put forward by experts in Catholic social teaching and by the highest Magisterium of the Church take on special significance -- proposals for joint ownership of the means of work, sharing by the workers in the management and/or profits of businesses, so-called shareholding by labour, etc. Whether these various proposals can or cannot be applied concretely, it is clear that recognition of the proper position of labour and the worker in the production process demands various adaptations in the sphere of the right to ownership of the means of production. This is so not only in view of older situations but also, first and foremost, in view of the whole of the situation and the problems in the second half of the present century with regard to the so-called Third World and the various new independent countries that have arisen, especially in Africa but elsewhere as well, in place of the colonial territories of the past.

"Therefore, while the position of "rigid" capitalism must undergo continual revision, in order to be reformed from the point of view of human rights, both human rights in the widest sense and those linked with man's work, it must be stated that, from the same point of view, these many deeply desired reforms cannot be achieved by an a priori elimination of private ownership of the means of production. For it must be noted that merely taking these means of production (capital) out of the hands of their private owners is not enough to ensure their satisfactory socialization. . . .

". . . A way towards that goal could be found by associating labour with the ownership of capital, as far as possible, and by producing a wide range of intermediate bodies with economic, social and cultural purposes; they would be bodies enjoying real autonomy with regard to the public powers, pursuing their specific aims in honest collaboration with each other and in subordination to the demands of the common good, and they would be living communities both in form and in substance, in the sense that the members of each body would be looked upon and treated as persons and encouraged to take an active part in the life of the body."

4 comments:

  1. I like your comment about having something to annoy everyone, hehe! That's quite right.

    As you can imagine, I have enough points of contention with John Paul II's writing here to take up the rest of the day.

    I'll just start with two:
    'property is developed by work for work' - No, property is developed by work for life. Property is an extension of life (I need clothing, shelter, tools so I can continue living or help someone else do the living). Once that is understood, then it no longer makes sense to talk about property as somehow inherently belonging to workers.

    Second point - what do commandments say about property, and how can a redistributionist Christian get around the mandate thereof?

    In my reading Eighth Commandment says "You shall not steal" (so let's not steal the business owner's equipment and give it to the workers, unless the owner wants to do so).
    In my reading the Tenth Commandment says "You shall not covet your neighbor’s house(!); you shall not covet your neighbor’s wife, or male or female slave, or ox, or donkey, or anything(!) that belongs to your neighbor" (so let's not even covet(!) the business owner's property, whether it be his machines, his buildings, his fields, or his house. Let's not even covet his salary).

    One response to my statement might be that Jesus somehow negated the Old Testament law. While we can talk about Jesus expanding on the commandments, we would be very hard pressed to find that Jesus does encourage forced redistribution of property. Voluntary redistribution - yes; forced redistribution - No!

    ReplyDelete
  2. It continues to be a question of whether the means of production can be said to belong fairly to anyone person at the expense of the livelihood of others. Having said that, I'm not sure JP II is arguing for forced redistribution as much as new business being set up along distributist lines.

    I have no clue what you mean by "work for life." Can you explain?

    ReplyDelete
  3. Those taking seriously the eighth and the tenth commandment cannot possibly attempt to lay claim to any producer's means of production. These two ideas are incompatible. Saying that means of production may or should belong to someone other than the person who bought them must come from some desire for that property (which seems to break the tenth commandment) and some desire to give that property to others (which seems to break the eight commandment.

    I will explain what I mean by "work for life" if you will first help me understand what JPII meant by "property is acquired first of all through work in order that it may serve work", which is the phrase I was trying to address.

    ReplyDelete
  4. Many would argue quite the opposite. They would say that those taking seriously the 8th and 10th commandment (which I know you do) place those in the larger covenantal context of the Torah. The injunction of robbery does not describe a government's responsibility to tax until we decide whether its in violation of other commands that God has also given. Thus, Ahab is condemned for trying to take the family's ancestral vineyards, but the Year of Jubilee, the yearly tithe, the 7th year remission of debts, and the prayer of Psalm 72 all defend the practice of redistribution (in some measure) for the common good of the people, the tribal families, and/or the poor. Paul himself in Romans 12:7ff places this responsibility of payment of taxes within the larger context of love of neighbor. (Indeed, the 10th commandment seems relevant here only if you start with the assumption that the means of production truly belongs to the non-worker. Otherwise, he has already stolen from the worker if he holds on to it past the acceptable time of use.)

    This is a good discussion for us to have because I think this claim is at the heart of almost all the libertarian assumptions you make about people and property. Biblically, a person may accumulate property, the goods they produce, and own servants to work that land, but only for a select period of time. Eventually, the land returns to the families who have lived upon it, and persons sold into slavery (unless they personally desire otherwise) are given enough to begin again on their own. I think all of this supports JP II's claim that "property" is not seen in Christian tradition as inalienable, though obviously he has the larger pattern of Christian practice and teaching in history.

    You make a good point--very Rabbanic!! a question with a question--about needing to define his phrase. (I thought it was a bit strange myself.) I went back and read the sections before it--12 and 13 primarily--and I THINK he means that labor and capital should not be separated because in the creation mandate of Genesis 1:26-31, as well as 2;15ff., humans were charged with having dominion over the earth and caretaking the garden, so he holds that work (i.e. vocation) is central to human nature, and that the produce and tools of that work are therefore endemic to it. The one who works is the one who partakes of that work's produce. I admit he may be saying more than this, so I'm not sure if I entirely follow him. He does express the caveat at one point, that the means of production should be owned by those who labor, "as much as possible," which would seem to give him some fudge room, I guess. If you have the time, I would love for you to read those sections yourself and tell me if you come to a different reading.

    http://www.vatican.va/holy_father/john_paul_ii/encyclicals/documents/hf_jp-ii_enc_14091981_laborem-exercens_en.html

    ReplyDelete